Microstructure of Securities Markets—Trading Systems, Price Discovery, and Determinants of Market Liquidity and Efficiency

tion of liquidity pools between competing markets can make price discovery less efficient and can increase execution costs for large orders.

Trading systems have different levels of transparency; in most major electronic auc­tion markets, there is a depth of transparency for price and volume of pre-trade bids and offers, as well as full post-trade transparency (real time volume and price, and identity of executing dealer). Over-the-counter markets (usually used for less-liquid equity markets, government securities, and corporate debt) would have less transparency, sometimes only post-trading. While transparency is generally encouraged, in some markets it has a reverse effect on liquidity because transparency can drive up impact costs for large trades.16

Trade execution rules include obligations to execute on a particular market or exchange, obligations to get the best price for a customer, and limitations on “internal­ization” of orders—orders never see the exchange floor but are filled inside the dealer by matching one customer’s order against another. In general, dealers should be required to get the best price for customers, although the best execution rule, as this requirement is called, can arguably interfere with the timely execution of an order. Parochial require­ments for execution in a regional market, for example, should not be allowed to inhibit best execution. Internalization of order flow is a controversial issue in most markets—deal – ers and banks will execute client orders either against their own trading books or against each other, rather than exposing the orders to the market. In some markets, internaliza­tion can drastically reduce perceived liquidity in the market (because executed trades are not transparent), but there are many arguments that customer orders are more efficiently executed at a fair price when internalized. Policy decisions to prohibit internalization are not necessarily the answer—it is far from clear whether exchanges (particularly as they become privatized) should be afforded a monopoly on liquidity as a matter of policy.

Quality of intermediation—how well dealers, asset managers, and advisers operate—in the market will also affect price discovery and liquidity. Intermediaries should be a reliable source of information (thus reducing asymmetry concerns) through their research func­tion and should, along with a sound payment and settlement system, ameliorate settle­ment risk. Without a strong research and advisory element in the market place, investors (especially minority investors) will not have sufficient confidence in the accuracy and completeness of disclosure by public issuers. Of course, adequate accounting and auditing standards are the foundation for research, analysis, and disclosure. Without adequate pru­dential standards, intermediaries will not mitigate settlement risk,17 and weak or absence of prudential standards will damage investor confidence and inhibit liquidity. Lack of prudential standards also may rule out margin lending and securities lending—contribu­tors to liquidity (Group of Thirty, 2003)18—because of the risk involved. Lack of ability to short sell and to invest in derivatives prevents investors and intermediaries from using hedging strategies or acting on all their information,19 and this situation, too, inhibits liquidity. As with rules governing trade execution, regulation of market intermediaries and disclosure regulations should be transparent and predictable in order to attract liquid­ity (State Street, 2001).

Market integrity (which promotes liquidity) requires entry standards that will protect the market by allowing only “sound” participants; however, unreasonable impediments to entering or exiting the market for either foreign or domestic investors will have a negative impact on liquidity. Transaction, infrastructure, and tax costs will also have an effect on
liquidity. Investors need assurance that holdings can be liquidated when the need arises, without encumbrance or disruption in the market (market failure) and at a reasonable cost. Barriers for cross-border trading, including transaction taxes and reserve require­ments, will reduce liquidity. However, once firms are allowed to cross-list on large inter­national markets, trading will be attracted to the larger liquidity pool, leaving smaller, less-developed markets with reduced liquidity.

Notes [23] [24]

15. Подпись: 11For a description of various microstructure choices see Glen (1994) and Dattels (1997).

16. For an analysis of pre-trade and post-trade transparency, see Ganley, Holland, Saporta, and Vila (1998)

17. By limiting access to the clearing and settlement of trades to properly regulated and well-capitalized intermediaries, the risk that a party to a transaction will default is significantly reduced.

18. The Group of Thirty (2003) advocates removal of tax and regulatory barriers to securi­ties lending. Another barrier may be weak prudential regulation, which creates risks in such activities and causes regulators to disallow lending practices. See also CPSS and Technical Committee of the IOSCO (2001).

19. Selling short provokes strong responses from policy makers. While it should be regu­lated appropriately, prohibiting short selling will act against liquidity and price dis­covery. Without the ability to sell short, a trader without a position can only buy and cannot act on information that indicates that price will drop. If a trader cannot act on negative information, the price discovery mechanism will be distorted.

References

— . 2004. “Recommendations for Central Counterparties.” Consultative Report,

CPSS Publications No. 61, Bank for International Settlements, Basel Switzerland. Available at http://www. bis. org/publ/cpss61.pdf.

Dattels, Peter. 1997. “Microstructure of Government Securities Markets.” In Coordinating Public Debt and Monetary Management, eds. V. Sundararajan, P. Dattels, and H. J. Blommestein, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

Dziobek, Claudia, J. Kim Hobbs, and David Marston. 2000. “Toward a Framework for Systemic Liquidity Policy.” IMF Working Paper 00/34, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Ganley, Joe, Allison Holland, Victoria Saporta, and Anne Vila. 1998.“Transparency and the Design of Securities Markets.” Financial Stability Review, Spring 1998, Issue 04, pp. 8-18, Bank Of England, Threadneedle Steet, London

Glen, Jack. 1994. “An Introduction to the Microstructure ofEmerging Markets.” International Finance Corporation Working Paper Number 24, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Group of Thirty. 2003. “Global Clearing and Settlement: A Plan of Action.” Group of Thirty, Washington, DC.

International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2001a. “Guidelines for Foreign Exchange Reserve Management.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Available at http:// www. imf. org/external/np/mae/ferm/eng/index. htm.

— . 2001b. “Issues in Reserves Adequacy and Management.” International

Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Available at http://www. imf. org/external/np/pdr/ resad/2001/101501.pdf.

Подпись: 11— . 2002. “Experiences with the Assessment of Systemically Important Payment

Systems.” SM/02/129, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

— . 2003. “Guidelines for Foreign Exchange Reserve Management: Accompanying

Document.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Available at http://www. imf. org/external/np/mae/ferm/2003/eng/index. htm.

— . 2004. “Liquidity Management.” SM/04/149, International Monetary Fund,

Washington, DC.

International Monetary Fund and World Bank. 2003a. “Guidelines for Public Debt Management—Amended.” International Monetary Fund and World Bank, Washington, DC. Available at http://www. imf. org/external/np/mfd/pdebt/2003/eng/am/120903.pdf.

———. 2003b. “Guidelines for Public Debt Management: Accompanying Document and Selected Case Studies.” International Monetary Fund and World Bank, Washington, DC. Available at http://www. imf. org/external/pubs/ft/pdm/eng/guide/pdf/080403.pdf.

Lyons, Richard K. 2001. The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.

Sarr, Addourahmane, and Tonny Lybek. 2002. “Measuring Liquidity in Financial Markets.” IMF Working Paper 02/32, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Schaechter, Andrea. 2000. “Liquidity Forecasting.” MAE operational paper/00/7, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

State Street Corporation. 2001. “Securities Lending, Liquidity, and Capital Market-Based Finance.” A State Street White Paper (December 2001), State Street Corporation.

Подпись: 11

Sundararajan, V., Peter Dattels, and Hans J. Blommestein, eds. 1997. “Microstructure of Government Securities Markets.” In Coordinating Public Debt and Monetary Management, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. von Wyss, Rico. 2004. “Measuring and Predicting Liquidity in the Stock Market.” Dissertation Number 2899, University of St. Gallen.

image092

Leave a reply

You may use these HTML tags and attributes: <a href="" title=""> <abbr title=""> <acronym title=""> <b> <blockquote cite=""> <cite> <code> <del datetime=""> <em> <i> <q cite=""> <s> <strike> <strong>